Add slides (no talk yet)

This commit is contained in:
rfl 2025-08-18 18:05:03 +02:00
parent 8272a1639e
commit b9df3994f1
Signed by: rfl
GPG key ID: 48B0E5DDF8FA62EF
15 changed files with 513 additions and 0 deletions

Binary file not shown.

After

Width:  |  Height:  |  Size: 188 KiB

Binary file not shown.

After

Width:  |  Height:  |  Size: 31 KiB

Binary file not shown.

After

Width:  |  Height:  |  Size: 18 KiB

Binary file not shown.

After

Width:  |  Height:  |  Size: 55 KiB

Binary file not shown.

After

Width:  |  Height:  |  Size: 57 KiB

Binary file not shown.

After

Width:  |  Height:  |  Size: 62 KiB

Binary file not shown.

After

Width:  |  Height:  |  Size: 73 KiB

Binary file not shown.

After

Width:  |  Height:  |  Size: 65 KiB

Binary file not shown.

After

Width:  |  Height:  |  Size: 77 KiB

Binary file not shown.

After

Width:  |  Height:  |  Size: 46 KiB

Binary file not shown.

After

Width:  |  Height:  |  Size: 63 KiB

Binary file not shown.

After

Width:  |  Height:  |  Size: 100 KiB

View file

@ -0,0 +1,110 @@
* https://forum.effectivealtruism.org/topics/land-use-reform
The problem
Laws at the local level in the United States and many other countries impose
strict limits on how much total floor area can be built on a plot of land. Such
zoning laws constitute a major obstacle to the construction of dense housing.
The resulting increase in housing prices reduces economic efficiency by creating
significant deadweight loss; increases inequality by transferring wealth from
renters to landowners; and reduces both wages and total economic output by
preventing workers from relocating where they can be most productive.
The effects of zoning laws on housing prices can be estimated by comparing the
sale price of housing to the associated costs of land and construction.[1] Open
Philanthropy has combined these estimates with rent data and some additional
assumptions to conclude that the aggregate "tax" on renters in five large
metropolitan areas amounts to over $100 billion in deadweight loss per year.[2]
A study by economists Chang-Tai Hsieh and Enrico Moretti examines the costs
resulting from the reduced flow of workers to more productive regions within the
United States due to rising housing prices. The authors conclude that land use
restrictions depress annual U.S. wages by $1.27 trillion and output by $1.95
trillion.[3][4]
If land use restrictions create these problems, why do they persist? In part,
the costs of restricting land use in a given location are incurred by workers
who would benefit from moving to that location, and who as such do not yet live
there. Since restrictions are created at the local level, they are insensitive
to the interests of these workers, who do not vote in those jurisdictions. Other
costs of restricting land use—such as reduced economic output—are dispersed
across society as a whole. Public choice theory explains why governments neglect
these costs and instead focus on the concentrated benefits to landowners—even
if, in the aggregate, the costs vastly outweigh the benefits.
Possible solutions
Open Philanthropy and 80,000 Hours have proposed a number of solutions to the
problems caused by land use restrictions, which are quoted below. Policy options
Promising options open to policymakers include the following:[2]
"Local governments in high-wage high-regulation metropolitan areas could
simply 'upzone', permitting more and denser development." "Local governments
could change the process by which they decide how to regulate land use. For
example, they could adopt a 'zoning budget' targeting an overall level of
housing growth, so that restrictions in one area would have to be balanced
by expansions elsewhere. This would help align incentives of advocates for
individual projects to support greater overall growth." "Decision-making in
land use policy could be re-assigned from local to regional or state
authorities, which would likely be less susceptible to neighborhood pressure
to oppose new development."
Funding options
Promising options open to funders include the following:[5]
Fund existing local groups, such as YIMBY Action, California YIMBY or Open
New York, or potential new groups in key housing markets. "Fund a campaign
to move land use decision-making power from the local to the regional or
state level. We are not aware of any existing arrangements of this form in
the United States, or of any active efforts to promote them, so this would
likely be an exercise in 'active funding.'" "Support the development of a
policy consensus (for example, by convening conferences or sponsoring work
on this issue in prominent think tanks). This would have the benefits of
both encouraging coordination on this issue by policymakers, and improving
our understanding of what policy changes are most likely to be beneficial."
* https://www.openphilanthropy.org/focus/housing-policy-reform/
We seek to reduce the harms caused by excessively restrictive regulations on
local housing.
Local laws often prohibit the construction of dense new housing, which has
contributed to rising housing prices and lower affordability for renters and
buyers.
Ratio of median house price and median household income in the US, 1967-2021 (US
Census Bureau). House price data is MSPUS; median household income is from
Income in the US Table D-1.
These price increases are pronounced in large, high-wage metro areas (e.g., New
York, Boston, San Francisco, Los Angeles, Seattle, and Washington D.C.). More
permissive policy which enabled a greater supply of housing in those areas could
unlock value by:
Encouraging economic growth through greater innovation and agglomeration.
Increasing the earnings of individuals moving to high-wage jobs in those
areas. Enabling more people to live in denser areas, which have lower carbon
emissions. Redistributing wealth and income to lower-income households and
supporting access to housing for lower earners.
Changing housing policy laws is unusually valuable because there is a huge
amount of private capital and firms dedicated to building new homes. Removing
restrictions on building — especially denser construction in cities — unlocks
that capital to be deployed much more efficiently without requiring
philanthropists or government to directly subsidize construction. Indeed, the
evidence is clear that “upzoning” (removing restrictions on denser housing) can
lead to increases in supply and reductions in prices, and several recent studies
conclude that building new homes (even market-rate homes) tends to make housing
more affordable, including for low-income households.
Considering these potential gains, we think that working toward more permissive
housing policy from a public-interest perspective (as opposed to lobbying for
specific developments) appears neglected in those key regions. We began making
housing policy grants in 2015 and were early supporters of the YIMBY movement,
which supports people to advocate for permissive zoning and development in their
local areas. Since that time, we have seen significant growth in the movement
and notable policy breakthroughs. Successes our grantees have been involved in
include: the growth of Accessory Dwelling Unit (ADU) reform in California and
Seattle, bills supporting middle housing and ADUs in Washington state, and
further legislative success in California for housing on commercial corridors
and removing parking mandates near transit.

Binary file not shown.

View file

@ -0,0 +1,403 @@
\documentclass{beamer}
% \usetheme{CambridgeUS}
\title{Rethinking Land Use: Effective Altruism Meets Georgism}
\subtitle{Mental frameworks for policy level interventions}
\author{Your Name}
\date{\today}
\AtBeginSection[] {
\begin{frame}
\frametitle{Table of Contents} \tableofcontents[currentsection]
\end{frame}
}
\begin{document}
\begin{frame}
\titlepage
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}{Welcome and Context}
\begin{itemize}
\item \textbf{Welcome!} Today, we'll explore Georgism—an economic philosophy
with potential relevance for effective altruists.
\item \textbf{Effective Altruism (EA):} A movement dedicated to using evidence
and reason to find the most effective ways to improve the world.
\item \textbf{Why discuss Georgism here?}
\begin{itemize}
\item EA seeks high-impact solutions to pressing global problems.
\item Georgism offers a distinctive approach to addressing poverty,
inequality, and resource allocation.
\item \emph{Land Use Reform} as cause area
\end{itemize}
\end{itemize}
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}{Motivation for the Land Use Reform Cause Area}
\begin{itemize}
\item Increased wealth transform from renters to landowners, reduction of both
wages and total economic output by preventing workers from relocating where
they can be most productive
\item Building permits, Zooning Laws and Nimbyism as structural roadblocks to
societal improvement
\item Surface Sealing, Car focus
\item Housing Crisis as everything crisis
\end{itemize}
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}
If land use restrictions create these problems, why do they persist? In part,
the costs of restricting land use in a given location are incurred by workers
who would benefit from moving to that location, and who as such do not yet
live there. Since restrictions are created at the local level, they are
insensitive to the interests of these workers, who do not vote in those
jurisdictions. Other costs of restricting land use—such as reduced economic
output—are dispersed across society as a whole. Public choice theory explains
why governments neglect these costs and instead focus on the concentrated
benefits to landowners—even if, in the aggregate, the costs vastly outweigh
the benefits.
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}{Why Might Georgism Interest Effective Altruists?}
\begin{itemize}
\item \textbf{Root Cause Focus:} Georgism targets the root causes of social
and economic problems, rather than just symptoms.
\item \textbf{Systemic Change:} Proposes reforms with potential for
large-scale, sustainable impact.
\item \textbf{Alignment with EA Values:}
\begin{itemize}
\item Promotes fairness and justice in resource distribution.
\item Aims to maximize social welfare and reduce poverty.
\end{itemize}
\item \textbf{Room for More Impact:} Land value taxation and related ideas are
underexplored in mainstream policy, presenting an opportunity for neglected,
high-leverage action.
\end{itemize}
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}{What is Georgism? (Preview)}
\begin{itemize}
\item Economic philosophy developed by Henry George (18391897)
\item \textbf{Core idea:} People should keep what they produce, but the value of
land and natural resources belongs equally to all
\item \textbf{Focus:} Fair distribution of \textit{economic rent} from land,
natural monopolies, and the commons
\item \textbf{Main policy:} Land Value Tax (LVT) — taxing the unimproved value
of land, not labor or productive capital
\item \textbf{Goal:} Reduce poverty, increase fairness, and fund public goods
efficiently.
\end{itemize}
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}{Why Should Effective Altruists Care?}
\begin{itemize}
\item Georgism addresses \textbf{systemic causes} of poverty and inequality
\item LVT is efficient, evidence-based, and minimizes economic distortions
\item Revenues can fund public goods, reduce regressive taxes, or provide a
basic income
\item Historical and modern examples show practical impact (e.g., land reforms
in Taiwan, Japan, and pilot communities)
\end{itemize}
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}{Georgism and Effective Altruism Values}
\begin{itemize}
\item \textbf{Prioritization:} Tackles neglected root causes of global problems
\item \textbf{Evidence-based:} Supported by economists for efficiency and
fairness
\item \textbf{Global Wellbeing:} Aims to eliminate poverty and promote
prosperity for all
\item \textbf{Systemic Change:} Offers a scalable, policy-level intervention
\end{itemize}
\end{frame}
%\begin{frame}{Today's Agenda}
% \begin{itemize}
% \item Brief history and fundamentals of Georgism
% \item Exploring core concepts further: economic rent, land value tax
% \item How Georgism addresses issues central to EA: poverty, inequality, and
% efficient philanthropy
% \item How might Georgist policies fit into EA cause prioritization?
% \item Critiques and open questions
% \item Q\&A and discussion
% \end{itemize}
%\end{frame}
\begin{frame}{Outline of talk}
\tableofcontents
\end{frame}
\section{A brief history}
\begin{frame}{What Is Georgism?}
\begin{itemize}
\item \textbf{Georgism} (also known as Geoism or the Single Tax Theory) is a
social economic philosophy developed by Henry George in the late 19th
century.
\item Core idea: \textbf{People should own the value they produce}, but the
\textbf{economic rent from land and natural resources should belong equally
to all of society}.
\item Focuses on land, natural resources, and the commons as sources of
unearned income that should be shared.
\end{itemize}
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}{Historical Background}
\begin{itemize}
\item Emerged in the late 19th century, rooted in classical liberalism and
political economy.
\item Influenced by thinkers like John Locke, Adam Smith, and John Stuart
Mill.
\item Sought to address persistent poverty despite technological progress and
wealth creation.
\end{itemize}
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}{Key Figure: Henry George}
\begin{itemize}
\item American economist and social reformer (18391897).
\item Author of \textit{Progress and Poverty} (1879), a bestseller second only
to the Bible in the US at the time.
\item Sought to explain why poverty persists alongside economic growth,
identifying private land rent as a key culprit.
\end{itemize}
\end{frame}
\section{The Law of Rent}
\begin{frame}{David Ricardo and the Law of Rent}
\textbf{David Ricardo (1772--1823)} was a prominent classical economist who
formulated the Law of Rent in his 1817 work \textit{On the Principles of
Political Economy and Taxation}.
\vspace{0.5cm} %
\textit{“Rent is always the difference between the produce obtained by the
employment of two equal quantities of capital and labour.”}
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}
\begin{figure}
\centering %
\url{https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=0yltJHY6g5I}
\end{figure}
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}
\begin{figure}
\centering %
\only<1>{\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{figures/rent1}}
\only<2>{\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{figures/rent2}}
\only<3>{\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{figures/rent3}}
\only<4>{\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{figures/rent4}}
\only<5>{\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{figures/rent5}}
\only<6>{\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{figures/rent6}}
\only<7>{\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{figures/rent7}}
\only<8>{\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{figures/rent8}}
\only<9>{\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{figures/rent9}}
\end{figure}
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}
\begin{figure}
\centering %
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{figures/calculator}
\end{figure}
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}
\textbf{Ricardo's Law of Rent:}
\begin{itemize}
\item \textbf{Definition:} Rent is the portion of the produce of the earth
paid to the landlord for the use of the original and indestructible powers
of the soil.
\item \textbf{Key Principle:} Rent arises due to differences in land fertility
and location. It is the economic advantage obtained by using a land site in
its most productive use, relative to the advantage from using marginal
(rent-free) land, given the same inputs of labor and capital.
\item \textbf{Marginal Land:} The least productive land in use, which earns
zero rent. All other land earns rent equal to its excess productivity over
marginal land.
\item \textbf{Implications:}
\begin{itemize}
\item As population grows, less fertile land is cultivated, increasing
rent on superior land.
\item Rent does not enter into the cost of production; it is a surplus
accruing to landowners.
\end{itemize}
\end{itemize}
\end{frame}
\section{Core Principles}
\begin{frame}{The Central Principle}
\begin{itemize}
\item \textbf{Distinction:} People own what they produce, but land and natural
resources are not produced by anyone.
\item \textbf{Single Tax:} Proposes a tax on land value (not on labor or
capital) to fund public goods and reduce inequality.
\item \textbf{Goal:} Economic efficiency, social justice, and reduction of
poverty by sharing unearned income from land.
\end{itemize}
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}{The few different ways to make money in the economy}
\begin{itemize}
\item Labor: You can sell your time to produce more of a valuable good or
service.
\item Capital: You can lend someone else your money, allowing them to make
investments that will produce more valuable stuff.
\item Information: You can do research, developing and selling knowledge of
ways to create more valuable stuff.
\item Entrepreneurship: You can take on personal risk and leverage the labor,
capital, and information of others to create new valuable stuff.
\end{itemize}
And then there's land ownership. You can buy land, and then you collect rent
from people who want to use your land.
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}{Problems with land ownership}
\begin{itemize}
\item (scarcity) there's a fixed supply of land. Realistically you can't
create or destroy land (surface, which a mathematical area).
\item (inelasticity) the demand for land is very stable. You can't decide to
just not take up any physical space tomorrow.
\end{itemize}
This means
\begin{itemize}
\item landowners are effectively always running an auction for land use
\item the rent for land use keeps rising to the highest rate someone is
willing to pay.
\item because you can't make more land, land owners get to capture more and
more value as the economy grows, without the land owners actually doing
anything valuable.
\end{itemize}
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}{Actually, there are a few other things like land}
\begin{itemize}
\item domains
\item patents
\item electromagnetic frequencies
\item satellite orbits
\end{itemize}
(my) rule of thumb: if the thing you pay for is more like a right of usage
than an actual item, then the market for it is economically similar to the
land market
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}{Land value is (mostly) the value of society}
\small{
\begin{itemize}
\item Close to essential services like schools, hospitals, shopping centers,
and recreational facilities
\item Easy access to public transportation and major highways
\item Near cultural amenities like theaters, museums, and restaurants
\item Safe area with low crime rates
\item Well-maintained public spaces and active community organizations
\item Strong sense of community with local events and activities
\item Located in an area with job opportunities and economic stability
\item Presence of thriving businesses and a flourishing local economy
\item Upcoming infrastructure projects or public improvements planned
\item Zoning changes that allow for increased development potential
\item Scenic views or natural beauty
\end{itemize}}
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}{General Moral Foundation}
\begin{itemize}
\item Everyone should benefit from natural resources and societal progress.
\item Privately created wealth remains private; socially created wealth (land
rent) is shared
\end{itemize}
\end{frame}
\section{Main Policy Proposals}
\begin{frame}{Basic Argument\footnote{inspired by this discussion:
\url{https://old.reddit.com/r/georgism/comments/1esw8l9/where_do_you_start_when_introducing_georgism_to/}}}
\begin{small}
\vspace{-0.3cm}
\begin{itemize}
\item Nobody likes taxes, but we gotta pay for some stuff, so we should tax in
the least destructive way we can.
\item Turns out, land has this neat property where we can't really create it
or destroy it, so it's almost immune to distortionary taxes.
\item Plus, land has this ugly tendency to get hoarded and milked as a source
of income for people who don't actually contribute anything to society.
\item Plus plus, because of the eccentricities of how land works, you can tax
land a fair amount before landlords can pass those costs on to land users.
\item So, we can cut a bunch of bad taxes, like income tax and sales tax,
replace them with a tax on unearned income from land, and make almost
everybody better off!
\end{itemize}
\end{small}
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}{Destructive Taxes - An Example}
\begin{itemize}
\item Imagine there will be a 10\% tax on apple sauce starting next year.
\item Producers are allowed to pass them to the consumer (as usual, and it can
not be prevented really)
\item Prices will increase by almost exactly 10\% (all things being equal)
\item Less people will buy apple sauce, even though the underlying demand does
not change
\item In a year's time, there will be around 10\% less apple sauce, because
here supply follows demand
\item Now imagine this for other, more important goods, like medicine and
income taxes that affect prices indirectly
\end{itemize}
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}{A tax on land value has no dead weight}
\begin{minipage}{0.45\textwidth}
\begin{figure}
\centering \includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{figures/dead-weight}
\end{figure}
\end{minipage}
\begin{minipage}{0.45\textwidth}
\begin{figure}
\centering \includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{figures/no-dead-weight}
\end{figure}
\end{minipage}
\vspace{0.1cm}\\
\footnotesize{
\textit{price ceiling} means \textit{price before tax} in this context\\
source (left): \url{https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Deadweight_loss}\\
source (right): \url{https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Land_value_tax} }
\end{frame}
\begin{frame}
\begin{itemize}
\item empty houses/flats will be put on the market because it is financially
reasonable to do so
\item additionally there is now incentive to building new houses on vacant
lots or add floors to existing buildings in high demand locations
\item the rent distribution will shift downwards
\item (small) businesses will have an easier time finding locations or
operating in the existing ones
\item people will move into the city
\item public infrastructure can be funded better
\item if land value is faithfully reflected in parking tickets, people will
park cars on their own property or get rid of it
\item tax evasion will become impossible
\end{itemize}
\end{frame}
% map of consequences ?
\begin{frame}{General Expected Outcomes}
\begin{itemize}
\item More equitable distribution of wealth.
\item Incentives for productive use of land.
\item Reduction in speculative land holding and economic inefficiency
\end{itemize}
\end{frame}
\end{document}